jprussell: (Default)
[personal profile] jprussell
Short post this week where I barely scratch the surface of what I suspect will be a big, deep topic - how cheap transportation has been the less obvious, but maybe just as important, side of the industrial revolution next to mass production.

Date: 2023-06-26 10:51 am (UTC)
thinking_turtle: (Default)
From: [personal profile] thinking_turtle

As a factoid, Europe now has fairly stiff import taxes for individuals. When I order anything from outside the EU, it gets a 10 euro administrative charge, and a 20% surcharge. These are considerable expenses.

One of the goals of technocracy is to create a standardized worker. I'm just reading Dmitry Orlov's "Shrinking the Technosphere", and he writes:

The technosphere defined It demands homogeneity THAT THIS IS so is clearly visible in spite of all the talk about “diversity” and “multiculturalism” in the overdeveloped Western nations. When people say “diversity,” what they really mean is homogeneity: a common, simplified, commercialized mass culture organized around nationalist/globalist concepts and symbols. In the pursuit of total homogeneity, “diversity” turns out to be quite useful. This is not a paradox but mere misdirection. Over time tight-knit communities tend to develop their own unique local cultures, traditions, languages and dialects, and these allow them to withstand the onslaught of outside influence. People who share a common local culture recognize and automatically trust one another. This is true diversity: the diversity of distinct, separate cultures with unique traditions of mutual aid, cooperation and solidarity. And it is this that makes them hard for the technosphere to dominate and to control.

The goal of equalizing every worker provides an alternative explanation for the dwindling of our sundry clubs, lodges, and groups. The powers that be are destroying mutual trust, transactions outside the system, and small enterprise. It affects the family, clubs, but also unions and parties, which have degraded to one-size-fits-all blandness.

Date: 2023-06-26 08:00 pm (UTC)
thinking_turtle: (Default)
From: [personal profile] thinking_turtle

Interesting. There's also the question of scale. Many more people consume many more goods than even 10 or 20 years ago. The urge of people to consume more may be the ultimate driver.

Date: 2023-06-26 10:03 pm (UTC)
k_a_nitz: Modern Capitalism II (Default)
From: [personal profile] k_a_nitz
Distribution was a lot more important historically than people realise. During the Napoleonic wars France blockaded English access to Scandinavia for trees to make the masts on its ships. As a result England switched to sourcing the wood from North America. But the ships bringing the wood back needed something to take on the journey there to allay the costs. Given the size of the North American market at the time bulk goods weren't really a very profitable option, so they took people - cheap fares for immigrants (see James Belich's Replenishing the Earth).

At the end of WWII New Zealand had one of the highest per capita incomes in the world (#1 or #2 from memory). This was built on the global distribution of agricultural goods - primarily meat, wool, and butter. Similarly for Argentina in its heyday, supplying animal products to Europe. For New Zealand in particular the lack of a large population has always meant that the costs of distribution have been much higher (effectively paying much more or piggy-backing partly off shipping to Australia), thus providing an additional driver for becoming a lower cost producer of animal products, if not the lowest. Take away the global distribution though and the landscape of New Zealand would be transformed back to that of the mid 19th century - marginal land, and some not so marginal, would almost certainly be left to revert to forest (NZ exports about 95% of its dairy production - who would drink all that milk if we couldn't export it?). The alternative would be mass migration at an unheard-of level (over 20% of the population of the largest city, Auckland, are already foreign-born and the housing market hasn't coped with that) - and the ability to build housing for those numbers is doubtful.

Whilst large populations can provide their own demand (the % of exports in the economy of the USA is fairly small, and China and India have the populations to act as a flywheel for their economy), for some of the major goods exporting countries the loss of global distribution would be world shattering in its effects.

Rolf Peter Sieferle wrote in one of his books (can't recall which off the top of my head) about the costs of transport in the absence of oil (which he called the subterranean forest), starting with the costs of a horse or oxen driven wagon, which needs to carry twice the feed required for the horses/oxen(and driver!) so they can return, and thus that needs to be deducted from what it can transport. He showed that this limited the effective circle of distribution significantly and also explains why navigable rivers (and later canals) were so important to trade.

Date: 2023-06-27 08:56 pm (UTC)
scotlyn: a sunlit pathway to the valley (Default)
From: [personal profile] scotlyn
Sorry, this is not a comment on your post, which I have not (yet) read. It is a comment on your question re Girard's mimetic theory. This theory seems to exert a strange attraction on some people I care about, and they will commend it to me as the work of an "anthropologist" (my BA, in the long long ago, was in the subject of anthropology). When I looked into the theory, it seemed to include a great deal of "backwards projection" onto so-called "primitive" societies, a trait that I have never found impressive. And, so, I decided to send a tweet to the then living David Graeber as to whether Girard could be considered to have carried out significant anthropological work. And Graeber graciously replied to me, (paraphrase) "no, Girard has not done any ethnographic work. Girard is, however, known for "forcing" the work of other ethnographers (not to speak of mythology at large) into the procrustean beds of his theory."

Date: 2023-06-28 09:20 am (UTC)
scotlyn: a sunlit pathway to the valley (Default)
From: [personal profile] scotlyn
I wonder have you read much of Graeber's work? I wonder on what basis you might have judged him to be "arch-Marxist"? And also, what this term means to you?

Yes, as I said, what Girard has to offer is very seductive in some quarters. I think it is because it is very comforting to the Christian view that the life and death and resurrection of Jesus represent a definitive turning point in the history of the world - that all was changed and that nothing after was or could be the same as all that came before it.

Still, his fundamental concept of mimetic desire makes no sense to me. How can we know what a person desires? And presuming we could know the interior state of another person, why would we not (say) want to help them fulfill that desire? What makes rivalry the automatic go-to response. Sure, sometimes... but always? Anyway, the procrustean bed that Girard forces everything into is the idea that the first truly human act was an act of human sacrifice - which murder then unified/bonded everyone who took part. And that this proto-human act was perpetually repeated in ritual and myth, throughout human history, until Christ came along and voluntarily sacrificed himself. And, while I think that it is true that some humans, in some places, have sacrificed one another, this is not true of all humans in all places. Needing to turn the first into the second is where Girard has to "force" his material.

Date: 2023-06-28 09:05 pm (UTC)
scotlyn: a sunlit pathway to the valley (Default)
From: [personal profile] scotlyn
As to Graeber, I only ever heard him self-identify as an anarchist, who is also an anthropologist. Never as a Marxist. :) As an anthropologist he was aware of being in a position to testify to the extraordinary and huge variety of ways in which humans have organised things for themselves. Which he took as a sign that the range of human possibility was, and is, huge, and not pre-determined, which is why anarchy made sense to him. This is what I most appreciate about his work - the sense that whatever IS, is not a sentence, nor is it inevitable, and that there are many, many, other possible ways... and that the possibilities are as wide and as broad as we let them be.

I do think that in "Debt" he firmly quarreled with what he probaby would call the Adam Smith "just so" story of barter preceding - and inevitably developing into - money (granted, he says, Adam Smith did not have the wealth of ethnographic material we now have, and was free to let his imagination rip when trying to figure this out). Because, he says, ethnologically, it is nonsense. Nowhere in any ethnographic source ever described from direct observation, is barter (in the "spot trade", or this for that, sense) ever actually found to precede money. Although barter can often succeed money, whenever folk used to trading in money have to deal with the money disappearing - eg in prisons. In relation to this detail, I think he may have annoyed economists of all kinds, both the classical kind, and of the Marxist kind. ;)

But also, it really IS a good book. Please do post something when you get around to reading it. I'd be interested in your thoughts on it. :)

Re Girard, yes, the concept that all human culture and mythology arose following the (purported) first fully human cultural act - a human sacrifice - is what really put me off him. Still, perhaps there are others who find something of benefit in his work. Who am I to say?

Date: 2023-06-29 09:12 am (UTC)
scotlyn: a sunlit pathway to the valley (Default)
From: [personal profile] scotlyn
Thank you - it sounds like it could be an interesting read. Although, initially, there does not seem to be much appreciation that the colonists who adopted wampum for money simply found in wampum a good substitute for the coinage they were accustomed to using (something like prisoners using packs of cigarettes as currency). The role that wampum played in native cultures is unlikely to have much resembled the uses the colonists put it to.

Also, there are a couple of "just so" stories from the world of biology appearing in this summary. ;) For example that you can understand society by centring "genes" as the [presumed] rational actors in your story instead of people. (Dawkins "Selfish Gene" book is actually one of the most religious books I have ever read by someone who is said to abhor religion!) And, the assumption that "co-operation" is sharply constrained in nature. Hmmm... Lynn Margulis had a great deal to say to that!

The most interesting part of this summary is that it barely mentions social relationships - which is the context in which all exchange between humans takes place. What Graeber (influenced by Marcel Mauss, Marshall Sahlins, and others) shows is that what we in the west have come to fetishise (the *things* that are traded), most people conceive of "things" in relation to the people from whose hand, or to whose hand, the thing will move. Goods that move from hand to hand, are only a part of a larger language of relationship.

The "distance" in time between the giving of a gift and its reciprocation (which is the "problem" that money is supposed to have solved) is not a problem at all when the two people involved are not strangers and have a long term relationship - long term enough to easily hold any and all of the long time gaps between a gift going one way and a gift going the other in a normal state of trust. The problem only becomes a problem if strangers find themselves needing to trade with each other - and [importantly] needing to remain strangers at the end of the trade. It seems to me that Graeber offers a much more sophisticated and ethnographically nuanced analysis of the many languages of exchange that people have used, and of which money (as we use it) comes down to us as one narrowed and impoverished [and also, incidentally, impoverishING] stream.

Yes... now that I think of it, I must take another look at Graeber's Debt book.

PS - thanks for entertaining this lengthy conversation! :)

Ralph Borsodi

Date: 2025-01-04 07:18 pm (UTC)
From: (Anonymous)
Hi Jeff,

I apologize for resurrecting a very old thread. I only just recently discovered your blog from your comments on J.M. Greer's dreamwidth blog.

The title of this post caught my attention. Are you familiar with Ralph Borsodi and his book, The Distribution Age (https://soilandhealth.org/book/the-distribution-age/)? Ralph Borsodi was an economist turned philosopher and a back-to-the-lander during the Great Depression. He, quite unpopularly for the time, identified this freight issue as a problem and described its long-term impact on the economy in detail in The Distribution Age. It is a very fascinating read, especially for those that have an understanding of retail and/or wholesale business.

Your post touches very much on the basics of Borsodi's thesis. I thought it might interest you.

In a side note, Borsodi left all of his works to the public domain when he died. This Ugly Civilization and Flight From The City are also worthwhile reads.

Profile

jprussell: (Default)
Jeff Russell

March 2025

S M T W T F S
      1
2345678
9101112131415
16171819202122
232425262728 29
3031     

Most Popular Tags

Style Credit

Expand Cut Tags

No cut tags
Page generated May. 22nd, 2025 10:07 pm
Powered by Dreamwidth Studios